CDN$ 28.37
Temporarily out of stock.
Order now and we'll deliver when available. We'll e-mail you with an estimated delivery date as soon as we have more information. Your account will only be charged when we ship the item.
Ships from and sold by Amazon.ca. Gift-wrap available.
Quantity:1
Ferraris for All: In Defe... has been added to your Cart
Have one to sell?
Flip to back Flip to front
Listen Playing... Paused   You're listening to a sample of the Audible audio edition.
Learn more
See all 2 images

Ferraris for All: In Defence of Economic Progress Paperback – May 15 2012


See all 2 formats and editions Hide other formats and editions
Amazon Price
New from Used from
Kindle Edition
"Please retry"
Paperback
"Please retry"
CDN$ 28.37
CDN$ 10.63 CDN$ 23.02

Harry Potter and the Cursed Child
click to open popover

Special Offers and Product Promotions

  • You'll save an extra 5% on Books purchased from Amazon.ca, now through July 29th. No code necessary, discount applied at checkout. Here's how (restrictions apply)

No Kindle device required. Download one of the Free Kindle apps to start reading Kindle books on your smartphone, tablet, and computer.
Getting the download link through email is temporarily not available. Please check back later.

  • Apple
  • Android
  • Windows Phone
  • Android

To get the free app, enter your mobile phone number.




Product Details

  • Paperback: 296 pages
  • Publisher: Policy Press; Reprint edition (May 15 2012)
  • Language: English
  • ISBN-10: 1847423450
  • ISBN-13: 978-1847423450
  • Product Dimensions: 14 x 2 x 21.6 cm
  • Shipping Weight: 422 g
  • Average Customer Review: Be the first to review this item
  • Amazon Bestsellers Rank: #1,443,663 in Books (See Top 100 in Books)
  •  Would you like to update product info, give feedback on images, or tell us about a lower price?

  • See Complete Table of Contents

Product Description

Review

"The global financial crisis has produced a fresh outpouring of growth scepticism; the idea that we would all be better off in a world without economic growth. Daniel Ben-Ami has provided a timely and thought-provoking reminder of why we need growth and the benefits that it brings." --David Smith, The Sunday Times. "No contemporary writer in English is smarter and more convincing on the benefits of wealth to every aspect of society. It's great to see a book-length treatment of his work." --Nick Gillespie, Editor-in-chief, Reason. "Daniel Ben-Ami is an important voice for reason and fact in our current economic debates. His book is a probing contribution to understanding the decisive way that economic growth helps everyone, everywhere on the social ladder. Ben-Ami's style is incisive and entertaining, his argument crucial to understanding our present economic plight. " --Denis Dutton, Editor, Arts & Letters Daily. "It is all too rare to find a writer who is consistently thought-provoking and yet not unthinkingly contrarian. But in his writings on the economy, Daniel Ben-Ami proves himself to be one of these rare creatures. " --Diane Coyle, Managing Director of Enlightenment Economics. "..an attractively readable, succinct and closely-argued optimistic exposition." --Society of Business Economists

About the Author

Daniel Ben-Ami has worked as a journalist specialising in economics and finance for 25 years, during which he has contributed to many national newspapers and specialist publications. In addition to having written for specialist magazines he has contributed to the Financial Times, Guardian, Independent, Prospect, spiked, the Sunday Telegraph, the Sunday Times and was previously editor of Fund Strategy magazine. He has also had numerous media engagements on the BBC and elsewhere. In the US he has appeared as a guest on the Al Franken Show on Air America Radio and his work has featured in Reason magazine online. Daniel has covered the rise of growth scepticism for several years. He has written widely on the subject, including articles for spiked-online (some of which have featured on , with extracts appearing in the New York Times and www.reason.com ). He has been a speaker at many events including the New York Salon, the Battle of Ideas festival, and the Royal Society for the Encouragement of the Arts. His previous book - Cowardly Capitalism (Wiley 2001) - examined the global financial markets. It was widely reviewed including, the Financial Times, the Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung (Frankfurt) and the Independent and endorsed by Business Week. It was recommended student reading for Harvard Business School. Since this book was published in hardback, he has been invited to take part in many debates and panels in the UK and internationally to present his arguments. His website and blog can be found at www.danielbenami.com .

Customer Reviews

There are no customer reviews yet on Amazon.ca
5 star
4 star
3 star
2 star
1 star

Most Helpful Customer Reviews on Amazon.com (beta)

Amazon.com: HASH(0x9ded93c0) out of 5 stars 2 reviews
1 of 1 people found the following review helpful
HASH(0x9ebf23fc) out of 5 stars Smoothly written, but with holes you could drive a Ferrari through (2.5 stars) Feb. 17 2016
By A. J. Sutter - Published on Amazon.com
Format: Paperback
During the 1970s, it was hard to enter the campus gates of any major university in Cambridge (Mass) or New York City without first having to pass through a pair of extremely intense, earnest people who wanted to hand you a newspaper. At places like Harvard, Columbia or NYU they were Trotskyites, and at MIT they were devotees of Ayn Rand’s cult of objectivism and romantic realism. I confess that during the past 40+ years I’ve never wondered about whatever became of those folks. Reading this book, I found out anyway.

1. LEFT-WING OR RIGHT-WING?: The author (DBA) was barely a couple of years too young, and on the wrong continent, to have ever blocked my way with his tabloid. Today he writes for a UK online magazine called “Sp!ked”, which was founded by a “libertarian Marxist” and which one of its leading contributors acknowledges to be influenced by Trotsky. (Meanwhile, the website runs headlines that could have been written by Ayn Rand herself, like “Gravitational waves: behold the greatness of man.”)

In his Preface, DBA presents his credentials as a man of the Left. Sure enough, there are plenty of hallmarks of a traditional 20th Century Leftist perspective in the book. For one thing, there are plenty of favorable references to Marx. In a 1971 critique of economic growth entitled « L’abondance est-elle possible ? [Is abundance possible?] », Hungarian sociologist Péter/Pierre Kende pointed out that both capitalists and socialists are devoted to growth, but the former emphasize consumption while the latter emphasize production. You’ll find the topic of production coming up continually in this book, both explicitly (e.g., @85, 97), and when DBA asserts that older economists’ use of the term ‘capital accumulation’ — which refers to assets used for productive purposes - was their way of talking about economic growth (@11).

Nonetheless, at times the book seems to have curled around so far to the left that it joins hands with the Right. How else to explain that it both absolves Mao Tse-Tung from blame for the murderous Great Leap Forward (in a context suggesting that the deadly famines arose from natural causes as yet untamed by the forces of economic growth, @158) *and* defends Wall Street bankers (@222)? How else to understand the contradiction that although DBA uses the word “conservative” as a mark of shame, he claims the true “radical” path is to stick to the line of a book written almost 170 years ago? (@240-244: The Communist Manifesto, of course.) And though Marxists and Objectivists might be loath to admit it, the book’s passionate defense of individual freedoms and an outlook “based on notions such as progress, the power of reason and the demand for plenty,” its “rejection of the idea that human potential is constrained by natural limits” and its call for “a revival of the project of asserting human control over nature” (@255) are equally Marxian and Randian. (Although Rand rejected the Soviet Union, her opportunity to attend university was thanks to the Russian Revolution: so it’s not surprising that she carried some rhetorical and even intellectual echoes of it.)

2. RHETORICAL TECHNIQUE: The engine of DBA’s argument, though, seems to be a tactic he borrowed from Saul Alinsky (not that I think ill of Alinsky). In Rules for Radicals (1971), Alinsky’s 13th Rule of Power Tactics urges “Pick the target, freeze it, personalize it, and polarize it.” DBA does exactly that by labeling the main targets of his argument as “growth sceptics.”

These must be people who are anti-growth, or who doubt economic growth is a good thing, right? Not at all. “Growth sceptics” as explicitly defined by DBA (@11-12) are *pro-growth.* Their sin is that they believe that there might be natural, social or moral limits to growth, and that maybe growth could have harmful effects on the environment or limited resources. (Nonsense, says DBA: in Chap. 7 he describes how growth “on balance” *improves* the environment, especially by reducing the adverse impact of nature on people, and how innovation overcomes all limits.) Even worse, “sceptics” suggest that that we should “downgrade” the importance of growth by taking an interest in the “well-being” of people, and/or care about what we leave for future generations (“sustainability”) instead of focusing on the “prosperity” of people today through more production. In all these things, they depart from “staunch advocates of economic growth” like DBA (@17), who don’t harbor any doubts about growth or the future. And while “sceptics” may borrow arguments from the third faction, the “deep greens” — comprising both ‘deep ecology’ environmentalists and the even more explicitly anti-growth degrowth advocates — that faction is merely a “minority hard core viewpoint,” which is unlikely ever to become popular with the public (@25). What’s dangerous about “growth sceptics” is that they are in the majority, says DBA. In fact, their rise has been a “long, drawn-out process” that began with “the defeat [sic] of the Russian Revolution in 1917” (@75). (So is the February Revolution is still a bitter memory for 21st Century Trotskyites, despite their better luck a few months later? I wonder if Red Sox fans have already forgotten about 2004 and are still ruing their earlier World Series losses.)

Is it really “scepticism” if people suspect that they have to be careful about how they pursue growth? Is your heart surgeon a “sceptic” if she’s very careful and focused about how she operates on you during a so-called routine operation? Obviously DBA is using a well-known rhetorical trick of choosing a term with strong connotations in order to bias the reader’s mind each time the word is repeated, while pretending the word or phrase has a more neutral meaning. (Actually, “growth” is exactly such a word, too — we might think differently if politicians talked about the economy “swelling,” for example.) To be fair, DBA does tell the reader that this is a polemical work (@viii); this sort of characterization is bread and butter for polemicists. Moreover, polemics aren’t always intended to appeal to a rational audience. If we try to weigh DBA’s arguments rationally, though, how solid are they?

Suppose we change the terminology: Since to be a “staunch advocate” by DBA’s lights you can’t entertain even the slightest doubt about whether there are any sort of limits to growth or about whether growth has any adverse environmental impact, let’s call him and his comrades “growth fanatics.” Let’s call those who are pro-growth but who are concerned about growth’s possible adverse side effects “rational supporters of growth;” and instead of “deep greens” we can simply call the same group “opponents of growth” (which is better anyway, since not all who oppose growth do so primarily on environmental grounds). If you read the book with these mental substitutions for DBA’s preferred epithets, then the substantive weaknesses in DBA’s growth-fanatic arguments become more apparent.

3. SOME SUBSTANTIVE ISSUES: First of all, DBA never defines “prosperity” — which makes it much harder to accept that rational supporters of growth really oppose it. And if “well-being” is irrelevant to prosperity, then is having more stuff - or, more precisely, producing more stuff — all there is to “prosperity for all”? (If so, then the next question would be: if I have 20 iPhones instead of 1, is that a sort of prosperity worth having?)

Next, even if we accept without argument Chap. 6’s recitation of growth’s wonderful gifts during the past couple of centuries, why should we necessarily expect that the benefits of growth *could not* be more moderate in the future? It seems to me that a rational supporter of growth would at least entertain the possibility of declining marginal utility of growth and maybe of qualitatively adverse impacts, even if a fanatic would not. By the way, many of those advances attributed to growth, including radar and a number of other inventions DBA lists at the end of Chap. 6, would never have become so widespread (or in some cases, even exist) without government spending - and in particular, military spending. Those factors are never mentioned as preconditions for prosperity, however.

DBA also makes claims that are highly exaggerated, to say the least. E.g., growth scepticism brings about “disdain for industry. Industrial activity is seen primarily [sic] as a source of pollution and waste rather than as the engine of wealth production. Well-being is seen as a much more desirable goal than prosperity. … Growth scepticism expresses a fear of the future and ultimately, a loathing of humanity.” (@86.) It gets odder: apropos of the US obesity epidemic and its connection to the American Dream, he notes: “What the growth sceptics find particularly offensive is obesity among the poorer sections of the US population. This is not, as they suggest, because they are concerned about the health of the poor. For the sceptics such obesity is perhaps the ultimate symbol of what they regard as a society dominated by overconsumption … [Contemporary critics] find the notion of the US as a land of plenty distasteful. In effect, they argue that the benefits of high levels of consumption should be restricted to a small elite.” (@157; BTW, is he suggesting here that obesity is a benefit?)

“Elite” and “elitist” are labels DBA constantly tries to hang on the rational supporters of growth/“sceptics,” who paradoxically are also the “majority”. How about the truly small elite, the “fat cats”? Hands off! “The campaign against ‘fat cats’ … is deeply conservative in the current environment. … Fat cats are typically set up as a populist moral fable against excessive greed. The clear implication of such campaigns is that they should behave in a more ‘responsible’ manner by accepting less. From this it is a short step to argue that everyone must be prepared to behave responsibly and moderate their demands. … [T]hose earning excessive sums are seen as straining an already over-stretched economy. Once this premise is accepted it is hard for ordinary people to demand that they should have higher incomes.” (@222.) And later: “[C]ampaigns against ‘obscene’ pay carry an implicit message to the general public: everyone should be equally ready to make sacrifices. Rich and poor alike should be willing to make do with less. It is a plea to curb general living standards rather than to raise them.” (@250.)

This is doubtful. DBA seems to be shifting the meme of “over-stretched” from public spending to the private economy, where I’ve never heard anyone claim it belongs, least of all rational supporters of growth. The usual call is to lower the rich while raising the poor and middle classes — not to cut everyone. But there’s a logical problem with DBA’s stance, too. Elsewhere he tells us that “the ultimate aim should be to raise the living standards of the poor to the level of the rich” (@115). So if we don’t do *something* to put a cap on the level of income of the rich, how can the poor ever catch up? The rich will keep getting richer all the while.

4. GENERAL: The book is clearly written, with little humor but a lot of passion, so that a reader who doesn’t step back and think critically about the arguments could easily get swept up by it. And even an objector to growth like me can agree that a few of DBA’s critical harpoons hit appropriate targets, such as environmentalist anti-growth arguments based on the laws of thermodynamics, and the “happiness” movement in social science (specifically regarding subjective well-being). The book includes many text boxes and chapter endnotes to flesh out some points in more detail. There's also a proper reference list, albeit a bit heavily-laden with DBA’s Sp!ked-mates.

For my money, the concise pro-growth arguments of the billionaire-backed Economic Growth: Unleashing the Potential of Human Flourishing (Values and Capitalism) by Edd Noell & al. (2013) seem far more modern and diabolically ingenious than those in this book: its Christian conservative authors skillfully twist the modern and compassionate goal of global well-being into a defense of the 1%. Nonetheless, this book is a valuable reminder that the pro-growth vs. degrowth debate isn’t a matter of right vs. left: there are partisans of each position on both sides of the aisle. I couldn’t help feeling, though, there is something quaint and even wistful about a book emphasizing physical production when its author writes for an online magazine. The struggle may have moved indoors from the sidewalks, but intellectually this book is too attached to the concepts of 40 — and 140 — years ago.
HASH(0x9e378b7c) out of 5 stars Two Stars March 12 2015
By Christian B. - Published on Amazon.com
Format: Paperback
dogs***


Feedback